Newsletter Subject

Where Are Interest Rates Going?

From

npr.org

Email Address

email@nl.npr.org

Sent On

Tue, Apr 18, 2023 11:01 AM

Email Preheader Text

The answer could matter for your home value, stock portfolio, and the future of the economy. -------

The answer could matter for your home value, stock portfolio, and the future of the economy. [View this email online]( [Planet Money]( --------------------------------------------------------------- The Life And Possible Death Of Low Interest Rates by Greg Rosalsky In [a recent episode]( of Planet Money, two leading macroeconomists, Larry Summers and Olivier Blanchard, debate the future of our economy. It matters a lot which one of them is right. The answer could have big implications for the cost of borrowing, your home value, your retirement fund, and the future of policymaking in America. Olivier Blanchard is the former chief economist of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and a professor emeritus at MIT. He is currently a senior fellow at the Peterson Institute for International Economics. Larry Summers is the former U.S. Treasury Secretary, former head of the National Economic Council under President Obama, and the former president of Harvard University. He is still an economics professor there. Peterson Institute for International Economics The debate between Blanchard and Summers can be boiled down to a disagreement about the future of interest rates. Are they going to go back down to the record-breaking low levels that we saw just a few years ago? Or should we be bracing for a new era of higher interest rates? An era, in other words, where it will be more expensive to borrow money, which could have huge consequences for the housing market, the stock market, and the capacity of the government to borrow and spend. The epic decline of interest rates Interest rates have [more than]( [doubled]( since 2020. This new era of rising rates is a dramatic departure from a long-run trend. For nearly 40 years, between the early 1980s and the early 2020s, interest rates kept falling. Not just in the U.S., but in much of the industrialized world. In 2013, Larry Summers put forward an influential theory that helped explain why interest rates had fallen so low and why the economy was struggling to recover from the financial crisis. He said our economy was experiencing “secular stagnation,” the symptoms of which include persistently low interest rates, weak inflation and mediocre economic growth. (Read our past newsletters about secular stagnation [here]( and [here](. The term was coined during the Great Depression, when the economy was in a similar funk to the one we saw in the 2010s. And, when Larry Summers resurrected this term in 2013, it was sort of a big deal. He was saying that mainstream macroeconomic theory was failing to explain what was wrong with the economy. That there was a long-term, structural issue facing the economy: weak private demand, which could keep growth slow and interest rates and inflation low, unless the government stepped in with significant intervention (namely, more borrowing and spending). In Summers’ explanation, the reason why secular stagnation leads to abnormally low interest rates was because, when the economy is experiencing it, something funky happens in the market for borrowing. To help you understand, here’s a brief primer on interest rates. They are basically just the price of borrowing money. And they’re very much shaped by what’s happening in the market for borrowing. That market is made up of borrowers and lenders. Borrowers typically borrow money to invest in things, like creating new businesses, expanding existing ones, and so on. Investment is the demand side of the market for borrowing. Lenders, which are usually banks, take our savings and loan them out to people to invest. Savings is the supply side of this market for borrowing. Savings and investment — or supply and demand in the market for borrowing — plays a very important role in how high or how low interest rates go. And, sure, the Federal Reserve and other central banks play a very important role too. But they’re not all-powerful in setting interest rates. And even when they do adjust them, they are usually doing so in response to what’s happening to the market for borrowing. In a recession, for example, people want to invest less, so interest rates naturally want to fall. In boom times, people want to invest more, so interest rates naturally want to rise. The Fed adjusts accordingly (with an eye on its dual mandate of ensuring price stability and achieving full employment) Before the recent surge in interest rates, they spent a long time going down, down, down. For example, the Federal Funds rate — the main interest rate that the Federal Reserve uses to try and influence many other interest rates — peaked in 1981, at [19 percent]( when the Fed was trying to bring down runaway inflation. By the end of the decade, it was just above eight percent. And three years after that, in 1993, it had dropped to around three percent. The last time it was that low was in the early 1960s. But it wasn’t done dropping. After the 2008 financial crisis, the Federal Funds rate pretty much bottomed out, going so low that it posed a serious problem. That’s because the Fed typically fights recessions and high unemployment by cutting interest rates. In the average recession, it cuts interest rates by about [5 percentage points](. But when the Fed cut it to zero, in 2008, that conventional weapon lost its power. Something weird was clearly going on in the economy, and it's what led economists like Larry Summers and Olivier Blanchard to gravitate to the theory of secular stagnation, which explained why interest rates had fallen so low. Side note: the Fed could cut interest rates to below zero, but it basically hits a wall somewhere near there, because no rational person is going to, for example, pay banks lots of money for a savings account (normally, the bank is paying you for that!). Negative interest rates effectively mean you’re paying a lot of money for other people to hold your money. Instead of doing that, you can just hold cash, and put it under their mattress or something. This floor for setting interest rates is called in macroeconomics the “effective lower bound” (originally called the “zero lower bound”). Listen to [our episode about negative interest rates from 2019]( to learn more. Same game; new rules The way that Summers saw it, the reason why interest rates fell so low — so low in fact that it challenged the traditional economic policy playbook — was because of a glut of savings and dearth of investment. Lots of supply and limited demand in the market for borrowing. It's a core aspect of secular stagnation. First, investment. When the economy wasn’t growing much, it meant that there was less demand for investment: because the economy wasn’t expanding a whole lot, there were fewer new businesses, fewer existing businesses investing in new buildings, machines, factories, and so on. Summers says there was also likely less demand for investment because technology reduced the cost of doing business. In the past, for example, corporations needed huge supercomputers and large buildings filled with secretaries and filing cabinets to accomplish what can now be accomplished with just a single laptop or even a smartphone. Bottom line, in the era of secular stagnation, Summers saw an economy marked by limited demand for new investment. But while there was a dearth of investment, there was also a huge supply of savings. One big factor, both Summers and Blanchard identified: the economy was seeing a rise in saving because people, both domestically and internationally, were getting richer. And rich people save. Second, many people, especially baby boomers, were saving for retirement. So we saw a huge supply and limited demand in the market for borrowing, and that, in this explanation, is what led to abnormally low interest rates. Larry Summers became, if you will, the chief secular stagnationist, and [as late as March 2020]( he was suggesting that secular stagnation would continue to result in slow growth, low inflation, and low interest rates for the foreseeable future. Secular stagnation, however, disappeared with the pandemic. Both Summers and Blanchard say it’s because of a historic amount of government spending, which boosted economy-wide demand so much that it finally dealt a death-blow to the core problem of lackluster demand that plagued the economy for so long. Sure, this spending got us out of the rut and helped people during a public health crisis. But, they argue, the government spent too much, and that sent inflation and interest rates shooting up. The way they see it, we basically went from an economy that was underheated to an economy that was overheated, and both economists agree that neither is a good thing. They both want to see a "happy medium" for spending, enough to defeat secular stagnation but not so much that it results in an unsustainable economy with prices shooting up. What Summers and Blanchard do not agree on is what happens next. As the pandemic and the pandemic-related rescue packages mostly disappear into our rearview mirror, a central question for Summers and Blanchard arises: is secular stagnation dead? Or is it just taking a nap — and about to throw off its blankie and come crawling back into the economy? In a recent speech to the American Economic Association, Larry Summers gave his answer: “My guess is we will not return to an era of secular stagnation,” he said. Instead, Summers believes, we’re likely going to stay in an era of higher interest rates. He thinks there are political and economic factors that have and will continue to reduce savings and increase investment. These factors include baby boomers now retiring (so less savings) and greater investment in green technology (which will increase investment). Summers' declaration that the economy will now likely see forces leading to higher interest rates was sort of a bombshell from someone who had spent almost a decade explaining why the opposite would be the case. Olivier Blanchard disagrees. He doesn’t see the deep forces that led to a 40-year decline in interest rates — including a glut of savings from increasingly rich populations building nesteggs for longer retirements and lackluster demand for investment — as just vanishing. He believes secular stagnation will wake up from its slumber and we’ll soon be back in an economy that looks like the one we saw before the pandemic. What this debate could mean for your investments The debate between Summers and Blanchard has important implications for us all. For example, Summers says, when we were facing secular stagnation, it meant there was a glut of savings and a lack of new investment opportunities. As a result, he believed, savings flowed to “existing assets,” like houses and stocks. It explained why, for example, corporations were buying their own stock (“stock buybacks”) instead of investing in new buildings, machines, and other stuff (capital) to expand their businesses. It also explained why we saw asset bubbles in the 1990s and 2000s in the housing and debt markets. So one possibility, he says, if secular stagnation is really dead, is that it will result in a “less happy period ahead for the stock market.” Also, higher interest rates for a longer period, obviously, would not be great for people wanting to buy homes, and that could result in lower home values. So Blanchard’s world of low interest rates might prove better for investors. It would also prove better for governments that want to borrow and spend (deficit spending). While they may be only arguing over several percentage points in interest rates, Blanchard says, that amount could matter a whole bunch for the capacity of the U.S. government to service its debt. For more, check out [our most recent episode](. Also, if you are interested in further reading, here are some of research sources for the episode: “[Have we Entered an Age of Secular Stagnation?]( by Larry Summers, IMF Fourteenth Annual Research Conference in Honor of Stanley Fischer, Washington, DC, 2015 (Speech given in 2013) “[Accepting The Reality Of Secular Stagnation]( by Larry Summers, IMF, 2020 [Fiscal Policy Under Low Interest Rates]( by Olivier Blanchard, The MIT Press, 2023 “[Back To Secular Stagnation?]( by Larry Summers, American Economic Association Conference, 2023 “[Secular Stagnation Is Not Over]( by Olivier Blanchard, Peterson Institute For International Economics, 2023 “[Summers and Blanchard debate the future of interest rates]( Peterson Institute For International Economics, 2023 Not subscribed? [Subscribe to this newsletter.]( Want to send this to others? [Share the web-version of this newsletter on social media.]( Want more Planet Money? [Listen to our podcasts.]( --------------------------------------------------------------- Newsletter continues after sponsor message --------------------------------------------------------------- Get Bonus Content [Planet Money Plus]( Subscribe to Planet Money+ for bonus episodes with behind the scenes takes, extended interviews, and extra facts we couldn’t fit into the main show. Plus, it’s ad free. You’ll get The Indicator and Planet Money Summer School too - all while supporting our nerdy, ambitious journalism. Learn more at [Plus.npr.org/PlanetMoney](. --------------------------------------------------------------- On Our Podcasts The life and possible death of low interest rates — Right now, the economy is running hot. Inflation is high, and central banks are pushing up interest rates to fight it. But before the pandemic, economies around the world were stuck in a different rut: low inflation, low interest rates, low growth. [Listen here]( Two mysterious bond market indicators — Right now, the economy is all over the place. And when things get confusing, we look to basic economic indicators to help explain what's going on. Today, we're bringing you two episodes of our daily show The Indicator that focus on the bond market. [Listen here]( Also on The Indicator: [Gloomy global growth, Tupperware troubles, RIP HBO Max]( [When AI works in HR]( [Prices: What goes up, doesn't always come down]( and [How one small change in Japan could sway U.S. markets]( --------------------------------------------------------------- Stream your local NPR station. Visit NPR.org to find your local station stream. [Find a Station]( --------------------------------------------------------------- [Subscribe to Planet Money+](. Your support helps make our show possible and unlocks access to our sponsor-free episodes. What do you think of today's email? We'd love to hear your thoughts, questions and feedback: [planetmoney@npr.org](mailto:planetmoney@npr.org?subject=Newsletter%20Feedback) Enjoying this newsletter? Forward to a friend! They can [sign up here](. Looking for more great content? [Check out all of our newsletter offerings]( — including Daily News, Politics, Health and more! You received this message because you're subscribed to Planet Money emails. This email was sent by National Public Radio, Inc., 1111 North Capitol Street NE, Washington, DC 20002 [Unsubscribe]( | [Privacy Policy]( [NPR logo]

EDM Keywords (212)

zero wrong world words way want wake vanishing usually us understand underheated trying try today throw thinks think theory term taking symptoms sure supporting supply summers suggesting subscribed stuck struggling stocks still stay spent spending spend sort soon something someone slumber sign service sent send seeing see secretaries says saying saw savings saving said rut rise right return retiring retirement results result response recover recession received reason reality reading put pushing price powerful posed political policymaking podcasts plagued place people paying past pandemic overheated one newsletter neither nap much money mit message meant may mattress matters market made macroeconomics low love lot looking look loan life led learn late lack investors investments investment investing invest internationally interested indicator housing honor hold high help hear happening guess great gravitate governments government going goes glut get future friend focus floor fit find fight fed fallen fall failing fact eye explanation explained explain experiencing expensive expanding expand example even era episode entered end email economy dropped domestically disagreement demand decade debt debate dearth currently could cost continue coined check challenged capacity called buying businesses business bringing bring bracing borrowing borrowers borrow bombshell boiled blankie blanchard behind basically bank back arguing argue answer also agree age adjust accomplished accomplish 2019 2013 2010s 2008 2000s 1993 1990s 1981

Marketing emails from npr.org

View More
Sent On

26/06/2023

Sent On

26/06/2023

Sent On

26/06/2023

Sent On

25/06/2023

Sent On

25/06/2023

Sent On

24/06/2023

Email Content Statistics

Subscribe Now

Subject Line Length

Data shows that subject lines with 6 to 10 words generated 21 percent higher open rate.

Subscribe Now

Average in this category

Subscribe Now

Number of Words

The more words in the content, the more time the user will need to spend reading. Get straight to the point with catchy short phrases and interesting photos and graphics.

Subscribe Now

Average in this category

Subscribe Now

Number of Images

More images or large images might cause the email to load slower. Aim for a balance of words and images.

Subscribe Now

Average in this category

Subscribe Now

Time to Read

Longer reading time requires more attention and patience from users. Aim for short phrases and catchy keywords.

Subscribe Now

Average in this category

Subscribe Now

Predicted open rate

Subscribe Now

Spam Score

Spam score is determined by a large number of checks performed on the content of the email. For the best delivery results, it is advised to lower your spam score as much as possible.

Subscribe Now

Flesch reading score

Flesch reading score measures how complex a text is. The lower the score, the more difficult the text is to read. The Flesch readability score uses the average length of your sentences (measured by the number of words) and the average number of syllables per word in an equation to calculate the reading ease. Text with a very high Flesch reading ease score (about 100) is straightforward and easy to read, with short sentences and no words of more than two syllables. Usually, a reading ease score of 60-70 is considered acceptable/normal for web copy.

Subscribe Now

Technologies

What powers this email? Every email we receive is parsed to determine the sending ESP and any additional email technologies used.

Subscribe Now

Email Size (not include images)

Font Used

No. Font Name
Subscribe Now

Copyright © 2019–2025 SimilarMail.